The Economics of Imperfection
"Behavioral Macroeconomics and Macroeconomic Behavior" by George A. Akerlof and "Information and the Change in the Paradigm in Economics" by Joseph E. Stiglitz, in _The American Economic Review_ (June 2002), 2014 Broadway, Ste. 305, Nashville, Tenn. 37203.
If you were an undergraduate between the 1960s and 1980s, chances are that the name Paul Samuelson rings a bell. An economist at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Samuelson was the author of _Economics_, long the most widely used textbook in introductory college economics courses. Economics embodied something called "the neoclassical synthesis," the mainstream doctrine that arose out of the post-World War II effort to reconcile the ideas of John Maynard Keynes and those descended from Adam Smith. The fact that _Economics_ is no longer the field’s dominant textbook suggests what has become of the synthesis.
Akerlof and Stiglitz, of the University of California, Berkeley, and Columbia University’s Graduate School of Business, respectively, shared the Nobel Prize in economics last year (along with Michael Spence) for work that has turned a good part of the economics discipline in a new direction. In their acceptance speeches, reprinted in _The American Economic Review_, they explain what happened.
The neoclassical synthesis—along with its updated successor, the New Classical economics—holds that markets always tend toward "general equilibrium." Whether the market is for factory workers or candy bars, in other words, supply and demand will eventually reach a perfect, albeit temporary, balance if left to their own devices.
In the real world, of course, that doesn’t seem to happen, as the theory’s proponents themselves have recognized and tried to explain (the Nobel Prize committee has also rewarded their work, as it did Paul Samuelson’s before). Akerlof and Stiglitz, however, proposed a more sweeping explanation than these defenders of the synthesis, under the unsexy rubric "asymmetric information." It suggests that economic transactions are powerfully affected by the fact that buyers and sellers—in, for example, the used car market—don’t all have the same information. "Information economics" is concerned with teasing out the implications of this fact in a variety of different realms.
One puzzle in the standard theory, for example, is why unemployment exists in the real world. In theory, if workers can’t find jobs at, say, a steel plant, they will simply reduce the level of pay they demand until the steelmaker hires them. But in a series of papers during the 1980s, Stiglitz and several collaborators argued that many firms aren’t willing to hire workers for less. Among the reasons: Lower-paid workers have a higher rate of turnover, which is costly. In such an environment, where wages are artificially high, employers have only one sanction to apply against workers who perform badly: They can fire them, in effect branding them with information about their performance that makes it difficult for them to get jobs elsewhere. Writes Stiglitz: "We showed that in equilibrium there had to be unemployment: Unemployment was the discipline device that forced workers to work hard."
Akerlof and Stiglitz believe that information economics can explain many other real-world puzzles: Why do people save too little for their retirement? Why are stock markets so volatile? Why do developing countries experience sudden, severe credit crunches? In a broader sense, Akerlof notes, information economics restores to economics the consideration of psychological and sociological factors that the neoclassical synthesis had driven out.
Yet, as Stiglitz observes, he and his colleagues are still stuck with an equilibrium model of the economy—their work just tries to explain why markets don’t reach the perfect balance that theory predicts. He thinks the future lies in a completely different "evolutionary" theory of the economy. Information as to what such a model will look like, however, remains imperfect.
This article originally appeared in print